Socialism Or Communalism?
|
Written
by Chinweizu
|
Wednesday,
14 January 2009
|
The Black race will be
exterminated if it does not build a black superpower in Africa by the end of
this century.
----------------------------------------------------
Socialism or communalism?
By Chinweizu
Several African leaders of the
“independence” generation advocated or implemented what they called
socialism. Prof. Prah reports that,
By the mid-1960s, practically
all African heads of state, with the exception of Haile Selassie of Ethiopia,
Leon Mba of Gabon and V.S. Tubman of Liberia had at one time or the other
espoused African socialism. Consistently, such ideologues have put a distance
between what they variously defined as African socialism, and 20th
century Marxian socialist formulae, with the emphasis on class struggle. Tom
Mboya anchored his definition of African socialism on the pre-industrial
communitarian ethos of Africa. . . . In Tanzania under Julius Nyerere,
populist socialism was described as Ujamaa socialism.
-- [African Nation, pp. 80, 81]
The “African socialism”
of many of these leaders was a prestigious misnomer for African
communalism. Here is Tom Mboya’s exposition of it; his is quite
representative of expositions by Nyerere, Kaunda, Senghor, Mamadou Dia etc.
“In Africa the belief
that 'we are all sons and daughters of the soil' has always exercised
tremendous influence on our social, economic and political relationships.
From this belief springs the logic and the practice of equality, and the acceptance
of communal ownership of the vital means of life—the land. The hoe is to us
the symbol of work. Every able-bodied man and woman, girl and boy, has always
worked. Laziness has not been tolerated, and appropriate social sanctions
have developed against it. There has been equality of opportunity, for
everyone had land—or rather, the use of land—and a hoe at the start of life.
The acquisitive instinct, which is largely responsible for the vicious
excesses and exploitation under the capitalist system, was tempered by a
sense of togetherness and a rejection of graft and meanness. There was
loyalty to the society, and the society gave its members much in return: a
sense of security and universal hospitality.
These are the values for which,
in my view, African Socialism stands. The ideals and attitudes which nourish
it are indigenous, and are easily learnt, for they have been expressed for
generations in the language of the soil which our people understand, and not
in foreign slogans.
All African leaders who have
written on this subject are agreed on these points. President Nyerere has
said: 'My fellow countrymen can understand Socialism only as co-operation.'
And President Senghor of Senegal, speaking at the Dakar conference in December
1962, on the 'African roads to Socialism', said: 'Socialism is the merciless
fight against social dishonesties and injustices; fraudulent conversion of
public funds, rackets and bribes...'
I have, I hope, given some idea
already of the reason why Africans call these attitudes 'African Socialism',
and not just 'Socialism'. . . . There is a positive desire, arising
out of what may start as a negative reaction, that whatever is of value in
Africa's own culture and her own social institutions should be brought out to
contribute to the creation of the new African nation.
I wrote earlier about the task
of reconstructing the economy in the days after Independence. In the effort
to do this, new values have to be established in place of colonial values and
we have to decide what part the traditional African social and cultural
structure can play in the country's economic development. Its main difference
from the European structure, which was of course the one officially favoured
during the colonial era, is that it is communal by nature. Most African
tribes have a communal approach to life. A person is an individual only to
the extent that he is a member of a clan, a community or a family. Land was
never owned by an individual, but by the people, and could not be disposed of
by anybody. Where there were traditional heads, they held land in trust for
the community generally. Food grown on the land was regarded as food to feed
the hungry among the tribe. Although each family might have its own piece of
land on which to cultivate, when there was famine or when someone simply
wanted to eat, he merely looked for food and ate it. . . .
When money was introduced, the
African came to work for wages; but he still maintained contact with his
native land as the only source of security to which he could look in old age
or in sickness. He was secure in his mind that he could go back to his home
and be taken care of by his people. It was a social security scheme, with no
written rules, but with a strict pattern to which everyone adhered. If
someone did not adhere to the pattern, and did-not take on the obligations
inherent in the system, he found that, when he next got into trouble, he
received little or no attention.
He was expected to live
harmoniously with others in his community, and to make his contribution to
work done in the village. . . .
The practice of African
Socialism involves trying to use what is relevant and good in these African
customs to create new values in the changing world of the money economy, to
build an economy which reflects the thinking of the great majority of the
people. . . . The challenge of African Socialism is to use these
traditions to find a way to build a society in which there is a place for
everybody, where everybody shares both in poverty and in prosperity, and
where emphasis is placed upon production by everyone, with security for all.
. . . In his booklet UJAMAA—the basis of African Socialism, Julius
Nyerere brings out clearly the essential difference of African from European
Socialism. He writes:
The foundation, and the
objective, of African Socialism is the Extended Family. The true African
Socialist does not look on one class of men as his brethren and another as
his natural enemies. He does not form an alliance with the
"brethren" for the extermination of the "non-brethren".
He rather regards all men as his brethren—as members of his ever-extending
family'. 'UJAMAA, then, or "Familyhood", describes our Socialism.
It is opposed to Capitalism, which seeks to build a happy society on the
basis of the Exploitation of Man by Man. And it is equally opposed to
doctrinaire Socialism, which seeks to build its happy society on a philosophy
of Inevitable Conflict between Man and Man.
--Tom Mboya, “African
Socialism” in J. Ayo Langley ed. Ideologies, pp. 508-513
---------------
Nkrumah differed from all the
others. Nkrumah, a self-declared Marxist, espoused Marxism, which is also
known as “scientific socialism”. He declared “Pan-Africanism and socialism
are organically complementary. One cannot be achieved without the other.” [RevolutionaryPath,
p. 127] Is that claim true? Nkrumah merely asserted but did not bother to
demonstrate this dogma of his. Unfortunately, it is false, as false as his
many fallacious claims about what “only a continental union government” could
achieve for Africans. It is like his opportunistic and Canute-like nonsense
that “if in the past the Sahara divided us, now it unites us.” [p.129].
Marxism (Scientific socialism) has as much organic or historical or cultural
connection with Africa as Hinduism, Taoism or Shinto. Marxism in Africa, just
like Christianity, is an alien, imperialist import. For either of them to be
organically connected to Pan-Africanism, European cultural imperialism would
have to be organically connected to Africa, which is not the case. As Prah
pointedly asked: “What is the relevance of ‘scientific socialism’ to the
notion of African unity? [African Nation, p. 63] If it has no
relevance to the objectives of Pan-Africanism or to African history and
culture, how can it be correctly said to be organically complementary to
Pan-Africanism? That Nkrumah was both a Pan-Africanist and a Marxist, is only
a fortuitous coincidence in his intellectual life. It does not make
Pan-Africanism and Marxism organically related in any way.
Furthermore, Ayi Kwei Armah has
argued, correctly in my view, that
Marxism, in its approach to
non-Western societies and values, is decidedly colonialist, Western,
Eurocentric and hegemonist. . . . Marxism, in its approach to the non-Western
majority of the world's peoples, is demonstrably racist — racist in a prejudiced,
determined, dishonest and unintelligent fashion. Western racists hold that
Western art is art, but African art is primitive art. . . . what makes
Western art civilized and modern is that it originates in the West ; what
makes African art primitive is that it originates in Africa. Racism is luxuriously
illogical. That is partly why, for Marx and Engels, communism is modern,
civilized and serious when it appears in Europe (even if it has only a
spectral form).The same communist phenomenon, when it manifests itself in the
non-Western world, is dismissed as primitive communism, even though it
appears there not as a fuzzy liberal specter but in human form — vigorous,
pushing toward birth in societies familiar for ages with communism as a lost
tradition and a real hope, often aborted, sometimes fleetingly realized.
--“Masks and Marx”, pp.
41-42
Since Pan-Africanism is
anti-racist, anti-colonialist and anti-Eurocentric, Nkrumah cannot be correct
in claiming that Pan-Africanism and a racist, colonialist and Eurocentric
Marxism, a.k.a. “scientific socialism”, are organically
complementary and that one cannot be achieved without the other. That is
tantamount to claiming that anti-racism and racism, anti-colonialism and
colonialism, anti-Eurocentrism and Eurocentrism, must be achieved together in
Africa.
In contrast to Nkrumah’s
“scientific socialism”, the African socialism of the other leaders is derived
from African communalism and therefore has a historical and organic link to
African culture. As Nyerere explained:
“By the use of the word
‘ujamaa’, therefore, we state that for us socialism involves building on the
foundation of our past, and building also to our own design. We are not
importing a foreign ideology into Tanzania and trying to smother our distinct
social patterns with it. We have deliberately decided to grow, as a society,
out of our own roots, but in a particular direction and towards a particular
kind of objective. We are doing this by emphasizing certain characteristics
of our traditional organization, and extending them so that they can embrace
the possibilities of modern technology and enable us to meet the challenge of
life in the twentieth century world.”
--Nyerere, “Ujamaa is Tanzanian
socialism” in J. Ayo Langley ed, Ideologies, p. 546
Nkrumah would have done well to
follow Nyerere and to heed Azikiwe’s wise counsel on ideologies:
“it is obligatory for us to
adopt a tolerant skepticism in respect of alien ideologies and then examine
impartially our aboriginal lore of good living. If we reacted otherwise, then
we would be desecrating the legacy which our forebears had bequeathed to us
from past generations.”—Azikiwe, “Tribalism . . . ”, in J. Ayo Langley
ed, Ideologies, p. 474
We need to note that both
Capitalism and Socialism are ideologies made-in-Europe to solve the peculiar
problems of a modern European society in which two antagonistic classes
confront each other, one having seized all the society’s means of production
leaving the other with only its labor to sell to live. Unless and until that
situation is replicated in Africa—and that would be a disaster-- these rival
ideologies will remain inappropriate for Africa. After all, theories about
the camel’s way of life should not be applied to the whale’s.
It should be pointed out
that the ancestral African political economy combined private ownership with
communal ownership. As Kaunda described it:
“ our ancestors worked
collectively and co-operatively from start to finish. One might say this was
a communist way of doing things and yet these gardens remained strongly the
property of individuals. One might say here that this was capitalism.
Collectively and co-operatively they harvested but when it came to storing
and selling their produce they became strongly individualistic. They did not
finish at that. When it came to sharing the fruits of their labour like
meals, for instance, they shared them communally. Indeed, one is compelled to
say a strange mixture of nineteenth-century capitalism with communism. Yet,
as is said above, this was original and the pattern essentially African.”
--Kaunda, “Humanism in Zambia”,
in J. Ayo Langley ed, Ideologies, p. 567
African Socialism or African
Communalism?
Why did these African leaders
choose the tag “African Socialism” for what was actually African Communalism?
I suspect that in the global climate of the 1960s which was dominated by the
intra-European Cold War, they found it prestigious to attach a European label
to their African-derived political ideology, hence the “Socialism”; but they
also needed to distinguish their ideology from European socialism, hence the
“African” in the name. But I think the time is past when we should seek to
enhance the value of something African by making it seem a variant of
something European. Our intellectual independence requires that we name
things correctly and on our own terms. I will therefore use the term African
Communalism henceforth to describe what has been called African socialism.
Towards an Industrial
Communalism
Nyerere, Senghor, Kaunda, Tom
Mboya, Mamadou Dia and the rest of them began the process of formulating an
ideology for building a political economy that would put in modern form the
pre-colonial African political economy of agrarian communalism. The project
remains uncompleted and should be continued from where these pioneers left
off. The challenge to work out an industrial upgrade of pre-colonial African
communalism is before our intellectuals and should be taken up. As Nyerere
put it:
“Who is to keep us active in
the struggle to convert nationalism to Pan-Africanism if it is not the staffs
and students of our universities? Who is it who will have the time and
ability to think out the practical problems of achieving this goal of
unification if it is not those who have an opportunity to think and learn
without direct responsibility for day-to-day affairs”—“Dilemma . . .”,
in Langley ed., Ideologies p.352
We should then invite our
students and academics to take up the challenge and provide us with the much
needed Industrial Communalist Ideology and thereby give us a framework of
ideas with which to solve our problems, with which to define and pursue our
interest in the world.
I would caution them not
to be put off by Nkrumah’s unsound dictum that
“Practice without thought is
blind; thought without practice is empty.”—[Consciencism, New
York: Monthly Review Press, 1964, p. 78] We should realize that Nkrumah’s
dictum is blind to the virtues of division of labor; it suggests that
thinkers who are not also agitators should be regarded as having nothing to
contribute. And that even a muddle-headed thinker who is an agitator is
preferable to a clear thinker who is not also an agitator. Let those talented
to think for us unabashedly do so. Let those who are talented agitators and
political organizers do that unabashedly. And if we spawn any of those rare
persons who combine first rate thinking with first rate organizational
skills, we should be thankful and get them to contribute in the way Cabral
contributed to Africa and Mao contributed to China, and Lenin to Russia.
For the benefit of those
who take up the challenge, let me stress that they should conceptualize our
situation in a comprehensive way, so that the ideology they come up with can
help solve our problems comprehensively. Unlike Nyerere, Kaunda and co, who
were trying to work out a communalist system, but who did not explicitly
impose on their system the conditions for defending it in the world as it is
today, those who set out to fashion a neo-communalist system would do well to
consciously design it so it can achieve the Black Power necessary to protect
it in this century. The mix of principles of ownership of the land and other
means of production must be consciously such as to allow the setting up of
giant industries. In principle, there should be no reason why a giant
industry should not be communally owned by an entire village or town. Modes
of ownership by communities should be invented to supplement and complement
individual ownership. In addition there is much to be learnt from the
Industrialized systems of Sweden and Japan and from pre-colonial
Asante. According to Prof. Opoku Agyeman:
Collectivism is the predominant
impulse in Sweden, in the sense that the system emphasizes the sovereignty of
collective well-being over individual private interests. In Japan, where
society is similarly conceived in corporate terms, individuals ‘are seen to
benefit only through the elevation of the group as a whole.’ In Asante, the
welfare of the national society was placed well above calculations of
individual self-interest and self-indulgence.
Prof Agyeman further
elaborates:
“The logic of the Japanese
“capitalist” system places a heavy reliance on the private market. And yet
Japan’s market economy is not based on Adam Smith’s notion “that a society
benefits from the liberation of individual greed—each person seeking his own
self-interest.” In “socialist” Sweden the government’s role has been to
foster social uses of ownership, which is overwhelmingly private, to ensure
the sovereignty of society’s interests over private interests. . . . In
“mercantilist” Asante, even though the public sector loomed larger than the
private, no rigid antipathy to private enterprise existed. On the contrary,
the private sector was nurtured by the state to generate wealth through the
fostering of a breed of private entrepreneurs.
Socially responsible uses of
the ownership of the means of production, private or public, is a
demonstrable value in all three cases. In Sweden, while it is acceptable for
a private owner of industry to create a fortune, this is conditional on the
wealth being used in socially useful ways. In Japan, the private sector
exudes social responsibility through a “corporate socialism” that confers
such benefits as lifetime employment and egalitarian job practices. In
Asante, private acquisition of wealth was encouraged but on condition that
the riches were obtained by honest means and hard work and could be relied
upon by the system for pecuniary assistance.
--Opoku Agyeman, Africa’s
persistent Vulnerable link to Global Politics, pp. 92, 90, 91
The great challenge facing
African thinkers, whether or not they are also political leaders, is to
fashion an industrial communalist ideology to guide the political economy of
an industrialized Black superpower. In this task, they have much to learn
from case studies of pre-colonial African countries like Asante and Zulu; and
also from non-African countries like modern Japan, Sweden, Cuba and China.
Copyright © Chinweizu
|
No comments:
Post a Comment