By Andrew
Robinson
Delinking versus
Capitalist Expansion
Samir
Amin, an Egyptian economist currently based in Senegal, is one of the leading
theorists of World Systems Analysis and dependency theory. He is a major
influence on the grouping around Monthly Review journal. His main contributions to
radical theory have been in the field of international political economy.
In
contrast to mainstream economics, which compares national economies as distinct
units or ‘billiard balls’, dependency theory views the world economy as a
single, integrated system. The system of exploitation of labour and the system
of states are indistinguishable.
As
such, the system of states is an effect of the global expansion of capital.
Hence, rich and poor nations are analytically inseparable; they cannot simply
be juxtaposed. This is as true in the present phase as in earlier history. Amin
views globalisation as an extension of capitalist imperialism.
Dependency
theory has been very much out of fashion in development studies of late; but,
in my view, this is for political rather than empirical reasons. The dependency
model still fits closely with the reality of uneven development premised on the
enrichment of globally-dependent local middle-classes in the South.
It
is very much relevant to the issue of
globalisation. It is out of fashion mainly because this stratum has
obtained power in most of the South, to such a degree as to make alternatives
invisible. Amin’s work is thus very relevant in understanding global
inequalities and capitalist structures today.
Global
Accumulation and Maldevelopment
According
to Amin, underdevelopment is not a lack of development. It is the reverse side
of the development of the rich countries. The rich countries depend on the
active exploitation of other countries, which renders the latter
‘underdeveloped’.
In
works such as Accumulation on a World Scale and
Maldevelopment, Amin argues against neo-classical economics from a
class perspective. In common with other dependency theorists, he argues that
the global economy systematically favours the continued enrichment of rich
countries at the expense of poor countries.
Throughout
its history, capitalism constantly expands. Amin argues that mainstream
economics simply theorises the management of capitalist expansion, and ignores
the role of social conflicts in development.
He argues that capitalist expansion starts at a certain place and time, but tends to expand globally.
He argues that capitalist expansion starts at a certain place and time, but tends to expand globally.
Historically,
it is divided into three phases. In the mercantilist phase (1500-1800),
international exchange is created, partly through the looting of countries such
as India and China. It is only after this looting that other parts of the world
‘fall behind’ European development. In the second, competitive phase
(1800-1880), capitalism expanded through competition, based on the advantages
it had already established. In the third and current stage (1880 to today),
‘monopoly’ capitalism, capitalism prevents declines in the rate of profit
through the mechanism of unequal exchange.
Amin
disagrees with Marx’s view of crisis resulting from the declining rate of
profit, which he thinks has been moved beyond today through the device of
monopoly. The global model is monopolistic, establishing monopolies for the
core countries on technology, control of financial flows, military power,
ideological and media production, and access to natural resources.
Unequal
exchange is the main means whereby capitalism reproduces inequalities. The rich
countries create an international division of labour in which they subordinate
and exploit other countries (Originally, they did this directly, by colonial
conquest). Monopoly systems lead to ‘super-profits’, above the level which can
be made in competitive markets. This means the beneficiaries of imperialism
can’t be out-competed in world markets. The global rankings are locked in
place, despite ‘free’ market processes.
Development
in poor countries in this context tends to be a ‘development of
underdevelopment’. They undergo economic growth, but in ways which do not
contribute to long-term development. Their surpluses are expropriated by rich
countries, rather than used locally. Today, major means of surplus-extraction
include structural
adjustment and debt repayment.
The
world is divided between rich ‘centre’ countries and poor ‘peripheral’
countries. Centre countries are less structurally dependent than peripheral
countries, and tend to produce mainly capital goods and consumer goods.
Accumulation in centre countries is cumulative over time, whereas accumulation
in peripheral countries is stagnant. This is because of differences in pricing
mechanisms for raw materials and produced goods. Produced goods tend to go up
in price over time, whereas raw materials stay at the same price or are
unstable.
In
addition, whereas wages in rich countries keep up with development, those in
poor countries do not. This is because wages in poor countries are not
connected with global labour markets, and because states in poor countries tend
to suppress social movements which would win increased wages.
The
global market is, according to Amin, distorted, because equally productive
workers are paid at different rates in different countries. Workers with the
same skills may be earning dozens of times as much money if they are in rich
rather than poor countries. This is unequal exchange: it exchanges one hour of
productive work in a Northern country for many hours of similarly productive
work in a Southern country. Amin does not believe that globalisation will
affect unequal exchange, because unequal exchange is the major motive for
companies to outsource to poor countries.
Global
capitalism thus integrates commodities and capital, but refuses to integrate
labour. This provides connections between issues of global policy and struggles
around migration,
which in principle could integrate global labour markets. Another recent
movement to address unequal wealth, from a perspective distinct from Amin’s, is
the Fairtrade movement, which aims to provide fairer
rates of pay for producers. Overall, however, the mechanism of unequal exchange
remains intact.
The
world-system functions through a division of labour among countries. Poor
‘peripheral’ countries are assigned the role of providing low-value inputs into
global processes, at below their actual value. The periphery specialises in
producing primary goods – such as agricultural crops and mined ores – which are
mainly exported to the centre. Unlike the centre, the periphery is primarily
focused outside itself.
The
agrarian sector thus tends to predominate in the economy of poor countries.
Furthermore, the local bourgeoisie tends to develop in a dependent way,
subordinate to foreign capital. A local (state or middle-class) elite, known as
the ‘comprador’ class, act as the local enforcers of global power on the basis
of their own class benefit in obtaining payoffs from exploitation.
A
series of economic distortions emerge, relative to the development of rich
countries during their own emergence into capitalism. These include
bureaucratic overspending, excessively rapid urbanisation, structural
imbalances within the economy, reliance on external aid flows, and the
redistribution of local incomes towards the comprador class.
The
effects of the global market are taken to ‘distort’ production towards export,
primary raw materials, and light rather than heavy industry. In agriculture,
peasant production is replaced by commercial agribusiness, which depends on
imported components and export markets.
This
does not preclude temporary economic ‘miracles’, but the long-term tendency is
towards stagnation and blockage. The structure is self-reinforcing. It becomes
impossible in almost all cases for a peripheral country to ‘develop’ out of its
peripheral position.
Peripheral
capitalism also differs from core capitalism in other ways. In the periphery,
capitalism is only loosely articulated with culture. While dominant, it is also
articulated with pre-capitalist economic forms. Amin sees Southern states as
operating in a partly ‘tributary’ mode of production with pre-capitalist
features.
Often,
reproduction costs (the cost of making sure capitalism has workers to exploit)
are subsidised by non-capitalist economies. For instance, childcare might be
supported in rural subsistence economies, allowing workers to be paid lower
wages.
Poor
countries are also financing their own exploitation. For instance, profits from
Gulf oil, invested in American banks, American government debt or extracted
through the profits of foreign oil firms, financed the recolonisation of the
Gulf by American forces. Dominance over natural resources (in this case, oil),
and in military technology, is used to reproduce global monopoly power. The
relationship between rich countries and poor countries in Amin’s theory is very
similar to the relationship between bosses and workers in Marxism.
Such
events have affected the rest of social life. In politics, neoliberalism has
disconnected the actual functioning of the class struggle (which is now global)
from the level at which political contestation occurs. Politics across the
world is resultantly empty, and is filled by distractions such as populism and
social conservatism.
Amin
refers to this trend as ‘low-intensity democracy’, since elected regimes have
little power in relation to the forces of global capital and therefore
conditions of life. He believes we are in a ‘hollow’ or ‘reflux’ period, in
which compromise is to be expected, and the conditions for rupture are so far
absent. Yet he continues to insist on a necessity to swim against the tide and
to refuse to yield to the demand for international competitiveness.
Amin’s
critique is similar in some respects to postcolonial theory. In Eurocentrism,
Amin argues that it is a mistake to view Europe as a historical centre of the
world. Only in the capitalist period has Europe been dominant. Earlier phases
taken as ‘European’ were actually centred on a Mediterranean region, which was
the core of the ancient world economy.
For
Amin, Eurocentrism is not only a worldview but a global project, homogenising
the world on a European model under the pretext of ‘catching-up’. In practice,
however, capitalism does not homogenise but rather, polarises the world.
Eurocentrism is thus more of an ideal than a real possibility. It also creates
problems in reinforcing racism and imperialism. Fascism remains a permanent
risk, because it is nothing more than an extreme version of Eurocentrism.
Amin’s
recent works have analysed the current, neoliberal phase of the world-economy
and the ‘war on terror’. In The Liberal Virus, he
argues that the network society is simply a lyrical outburst of ideology. The
reality is an increasingly stark global apartheid. He also argues that the
concept of ‘poverty’ is problematic in its assertion of a brute fact.
According
to Amin, the poor are not simply lacking, they are actively impoverished by
processes which are constantly reproduced, and which are getting worse. Hence,
he refers not to poverty but to ‘pauperisation’. He argues that the global
popular classes are increasingly being pauperised through resource grabs and
surplus extraction.
In
analysing the ‘war on terror’, Amin suggests that it is an effect of a
particular historical conjuncture. The especially crude American version of
capitalism, lacking in nuances and long-term perspectives, is seeking to
globalise itself through resource grabs. This is partly to compensate for its
uncompetitiveness relative to other central capitalisms.
America
is also taken to have an extreme ideology in which the existence of others is
conditional on not obstructing the American ‘herrenvolk’ in taking what it
needs. He argues that American aggression should be contained by an alliance of
other states. He also argues that a split has emerged between an integrated
core economy and a political system dominated by one state. America has taken
on the role of policing the world economy by suppressing peripheral revolt.
Nationalism
is criticised as a bourgeois ideology, through which the proletariat are
integrated into nation-states. The nation did not pre-exist the nation-state.
It is a product of capitalism, and was created by state violence as well as
capitalist markets. It is also incomplete. It assimilates to the nation the
virtues formerly claimed by the aristocrat, leading to racism and jingoism.
Nationalism
was artificially exported to Eastern Europe and much of the South: it does not
spread everywhere due to capitalism. The state is the actor which sometimes
creates or recreates the nation, and sometimes fails to do so. Amin does not believe
that liberation movements in the South are nationalist. However, he sees
possibilities for nationalist and populist currents to be drawn into movements
for “delinking”.
Amin
also dismisses ‘fundamentalisms’ and ethno-nationalisms as politically reactionary
and irrational. They are simply something people use to fill the vacuum of the
lack of class politics. For instance, he analyses political Islam as primarily
a form of cultural belonging through a ritual assertion of group membership.
This
obscures actual class dichotomies. While political Islamists provide some
effective services, these are ultimately simply charity because they fail to
provide means to destroy the conditions which create misery to begin with.
Furthermore, political Islamists tend in the last instance to side with
capitalism and with elite interests in Muslim countries. He also denies they
have their own theory of political economy. Rather, they reproduce features of
the tributary mode of production. He also considers Green thought to be a
variety of fundamentalism, mainly based on a superficial reading of certain
theorists.
In
his works before the current phase, Amin also gave considerable attention to
the eastern bloc. Eastern European and Chinese ‘socialism’ was a stage of
separation from the world economy to pursue autocentric development. They did
this in pursuit of rationalities separate from capitalism, though he maintains
Eastern Europe was actually statist rather than socialist in its economics.
Amin has been proven wrong on his view that reintegration of the eastern bloc
into global capitalism is unlikely.
Amin
also theorises further divisions into stages, based partly on Kondratieff wave
theory. The current composition of the world-system was created after World War
2, with America as the global leader. This phase was expanded from 1945-55, and
was expanded through autonomy movements in the poor countries.
During
this ‘Bandung era’ (1955-75), poor countries tried to ‘catch up’ with rich
countries through industrialisation on unequal terms. The third period
(1976-91) saw the three pillars of this world order – Fordism, Soviet growth
and the Bandung project – go into crisis. Capitalism has responded to this
crisis in the current period with neoliberalism – attacking wages and welfare
provision, and curtailing the economy which peripheral elites had obtained.
Capital has shown that it prefers second place in a world market to first place
in an autonomous economy.
Amin
refers to one effects of neoliberalism as ‘recompradorisation’ – the
restoration of the comprador nature of local elites in peripheral countries,
through the destruction of their autonomy. According to Amin, peripheries have
now been industrialised, but are still subordinated to the centre’s monopolies.
He also believes capitalism has been disintegrating for most of the last
century.
Amin
insists on the importance of struggle to a greater degree than many
world-systems analysts. He criticises other world-systems analysts, such as
Arrighi, for seeing capitalism as more inexorable and total than it actually
is. Amin believes that history is created through a series of clashes between
the capitalist logic and social forces which resist it, which he terms
‘anti-systemic’ forces. The latter make history as much as does capitalism.
Indeed, future developments are mostly shaped from the outside in, starting
from resistance at the periphery.
Andrew
Robinson is a political theorist and activist
based in the UK. His book Power,
Resistance and Conflict in the Contemporary World: Social Movements, Networks
and Hierarchies (co-authored
with Athina Karatzogianni) was published in Sep 2009 by Routledge. His ‘In
Theory’ column appears every other Friday.
By Andrew
Robinson
Delinking
Amin’s
alternative to global capitalism is constructed around the concept of
delinking. Amin calls for each country to delink from the world economy and
subordinate global relations to domestic development priorities, creating
‘autocentric’ development. This does not necessarily mean refusing external
contact, but insulating domestic policies from external economic power (It does
not necessarily require autarky). It is meant to involve a national ‘law of
value’ which is both ‘rational’ and has ‘popular relevance’, defined without
reference to the global ‘law of value’ of the capitalist system. In other
words, it involves creating a national economy with different rules from the
global economy. Domestic economic priorities must be set without reference to
global capitalist demands.
The
argument for delinking links to a conjuncture where neo-colonialism has
replaced classical colonialism. Independent states exist in the global South,
with relative autonomy from the world-system. But the old pattern of
‘development’ causing ‘underdevelopment’ has continued. Delinking uses the
autonomy won by peripheral countries as a lever against systemic power.
Amin
believes that delinking could destroy the world-system from the outside in. He
sees it as the only possible path to a different world order and a supersession
of global capitalism. The possibility of global change is thus rooted, not at
the heart of capitalism as Marx maintained, but in the peripheral countries.
Amin believes that the need to question capitalism is felt most sharply in the
periphery. The centre-periphery division is the primary, or most explosive,
contradiction in the current world.
It
also aims to expand the autonomy of nations, peoples and exploited classes.
According to Amin, the decomposition of the existing world-system is necessary
for a new world system to be created. It is illusory to seek rebuilding without
first delinking. Delinking would involve abolishing dominant forms of private
ownership, taking agriculture as central to the economy, and refusing land
grabs for industrialisation.
Instead
of defining value by dominant prices in the world – which result from
productivity in the rich countries – Amin suggests that value in each country
should be set so that agricultural and industrial workers are paid by their
input into the society’s net output. The main effect of this move would be to
raise wages in agriculture. Amin sees national states redistributing resources
between sectors, and centralising and distributing a surplus. Full employment
should be guaranteed, and the exodus from rural to urban areas discouraged.
Playing
to ‘comparative advantage’ (the driving force of the global economy) would be
reduced. Instead, attempts would be made to avoid deficits in basic goods. For
instance, a country following this strategy would not usually become dependent
on imported food. In contrast, many globalising countries have lost their ‘food
sovereignty’ and
become dependent on imported food.
Delinking
could either lead to socialism, or to a more egalitarian capitalism. It is
likely to occur through the power of the popular classes, rather than the
bourgeoisie. Ultimately, it can only avoid a return to international values if
it goes down a socialist path. Amin calls for a socialist delinking. He hopes
that capitalism can be comprehensively overthrown. However, he seeks for an
eventual return to a different kind of world-economy or world-system.
Amin
still assumes a historical progression of stages. He is seeking a passage from
one stage of the world to another, similar to the passage from tributary production
to capitalism. Although he seeks respect for different paths to development,
Amin denounces the ‘right to difference’ and maintains what he terms a
‘universalist ambition’, complete with modernist tropes such as progress,
reason, law and justice. In relation to postcolonial and poststructuralist
critiques, Amin’s approach looks decidedly continuous with capitalist
modernity.
Delinking
will be carried out by a new social subject: the popular liberation movement.
This is defined against both traditional classes (which are too national to be
of use) and nations (which are caught-up in the world-system). It is connected
to the popular classes (poor peasants, marginal workers and the urban poor) who
are affected by pauperisation. Delinking is thus a politics of the excluded,
but of a type which goes by way of state power.
Preconditions
for delinking include the development of a political will for egalitarian
reform – the main reason delinking has not happened in countries like Brazil
and India. Amin expects delinking to come from a strong national and popular
component in state-formation. The main ‘losers’ in this arrangement would be
the middle-class who sustain consumption based on global flows and models.
It
also requires progress in the fields of democracy and collective rights,
pan-Third World unity, and self-reliance of each nation. The achievement of a
multipolar world is also a desirable means to the end of delinking. It also
involves a strong form of non-alignment, though various tactical compromises
are permitted.
Delinking
is not the same as autarky. A country which delinks need not reject foreign
technology, but at the same time, is more likely to seek to balance it with
local technological development. It should pursue industrialisation at the
service of agricultural development.
Amin
rejects criticisms that delinking repeats older import-substitution models. The
apparent failure of delinking in Africa and Asia is, according to Amin,
illusory. The newly independent postcolonial regimes did not, Amin argues,
delink. They increased imports of technology, capital imports and state debt.
Nascent delinkings were actually cut short violently by the debt crisis.
A
similar politics is possible in rich countries. For the North, delinking is
defined by models of alternative development, anti-globalisation, and pacifism.
Northern countries can only delink if they break with capitalism entirely.
Europe also faces a cultural battle to preserve its distinctiveness against an
American cultural onslaught. This onslaught is viewed as attempting to
reproduce America’s aggressive nationalism and rejection of welfare states
within Europe.
In
the North, the dominant project since the 1980s has been insertion in the world
market. This has gone in line with restructuring in accordance with dominant
capitalist priorities. A Keynesian response is not possible because it prevents
capitalist restructuring. Furthermore, any global redistribution requires
reduced consumption in the core countries. The social-democrats have failed,
because they lack space for their traditional responses. Hence, they tend to
fall into Third Way conformity, barely different from neoliberals.
Amin
suggests that the only viable responses in the North move beyond the commodity
economy – for instance, Green proposals for economic decentralisation, moves
towards industrial policies disconnected from financial profitability,
autocentric development within European countries, or the broadening of
non-commodity opportunities.
Amin
believes there is a stark choice between an alternative trajectory based on
delinking, and the continuation of a barbaric world-system which is a mortal
threat to the global poor. As long as the system is not overthrown, it will
keep reproducing itself through genocide and dispossession. Amin sees the issue
as a very sharp choice between two poles: socialism (through delinking) or
barbarism, including the self-destruction of humanity.
Discussion
Amin
is sometimes criticised (by authors such as Sheila Smith and Ira Gerstein) for
overemphasising exploitation through uneven exchange, to the exclusion of
exploitation at the level of production and exploitation at the national level.
While it is untrue that he neglects class divisions within society, and while
production certainly has a place in his theory, it is true that he places an
overwhelming emphasis on exchange and on the global level. Delinking would
address problems in exchange, without necessarily redressing those in
production. It is also questionable whether it would redress power-asymmetries
within ‘nations’ in which it occurs.
Another
question which could be raised is whether the rapid growth of countries such as
China, India, Singapore and Korea, or the growing importance of global cities
in some peripheral countries, has destroyed the old centre-periphery division.
These are common reasons why theories such as Amin’s are unfashionable today.
I
would respond that dependency theory has already handled such obejctions.
Firstly, growth in countries such as India and China has been highly uneven.
Tiny pockets of ‘advanced’ production exist alongside massive ‘underdeveloped’
regions. Secondly, growth has continued to be premised on low wages. Thirdly,
while global cities in East Asia and China rival those of Europe and America in
the density of trade flows, command and control functions remain centralised in
the old core countries. Fourthly, there are geopolitical reasons why certain
East Asian countries (especially small ones like Singapore and Hong Kong) have
been allowed to raise wages above those typical of the South. Fifthly, these
growth ‘miracles’ are deeply unstable, dependent on footloose global financial
flows – as the 1999 East Asian crisis, and similar events in Mexico, Russia and
Argentina have shown.
The
general pattern of globalisation confirms Amin’s account: average incomes have
increased, but this increase is concentrated in the middle-class. Further, it
mainly consists of increased availability of imported consumer goods. The poor
are either getting poorer or staying where they are. If the ‘social wage’,
income security, subsistence, and cost of living are considered, there can be
little question that most people in poor countries are becoming worse-off, in
spite of economic growth.
In
China for instance, major coastal cities have undergone rapid enrichment, but
unskilled workers have seen only small income rises. On the other hand, people
have lost jobs-for-life, access to land, free housing, and state welfare
provision. Growth is still stagnant in rural areas. Millions have been
displaced from rural areas by land grabs and pollution. China has gone from
self-sufficiency in food production to importing food.
Although
China entered into globalisation to build up state power, and remained
determined to protect its independence, the actual effect has been the
opposite. Its ability to set an independent foreign policy line has been
undermined by dependence on oil imports and foreign investors.
A
more significant problem is Amin’s rejection of many of the developments in critical
theory of the last 50 years. Amin is an unrecalcitrant modernist. Although he
opposes dominant developmentalist narratives, he is ultimately in favour of
developmentalism. He also believes in eventual progress towards a world-system
which is fully inclusive and socialist. In other words, he remains within a
framework of concentrated power, even while criticising existing
power-distributions.
The
future sought by states which delink is assumed to be a future of economic
development along lines similar to those of the North, though more egalitarian.
For critics with a deeper sense of the problems with capitalism – its
instrumentalism, its alienation of social life its subordination to objects,
its hostility to subjective knowledge and ecology – the link has only partially
been broken. There is a need to abolish the law of value far more deeply than
Amin suggests. In many respects, Amin’s approach is followed through and
radicalised by ecologically-oriented authors such as Maria Mies.
Despite
his critique of nationalism, Amin continues to rely on national forces as the
source of delinking. Questions can be asked regarding his theory of the state.
If each state is formed as a colonial entity, forcibly integrating territories
in hierarchical ways, it makes sense that states also link into the
world-system externally. In Amin’s model, states remain determinant, for
instance, of the value of activities through national wage-setting. Peasants
are rewarded for contributing to ‘national’ output. This is still in many
respects a capitalist society, but one where the state takes a greater role in
production.
On
the level of power, the problem would be how to ensure that states actually
favour development and equality, instead of falling into the neo-patrimonial
patterns which are all too common both in imperialist and anti-imperialist
states. In other words, how to prevent power-holders in the state from grabbing
resources for their own enrichment. It would seem that, for this to be
prevented, popular movements would have to exercise considerable power over and
against the state. Yet it is difficult to see how this could occur with
economic power held so firmly by the state.
Amin
tends to assume that theories fall into one of three camps: Marxist, bourgeois
(such as mainstream economics), or fundamentalist (meaning reactionary, and
seeking a return to tributary production, and/or nostalgic and essentialist
about culture). I would suggest the actual theoretical field is far more
diverse, particularly in relation to poststructuralism, postcolonialism,
anarchisms of various kinds, indigenous worldviews, and theories connected to
social movements.
It
is possible to reject the Marxist baggage of stages, progress, economic
advancement and residual statism without replacing these with essentialised
cultures or earlier forms of oppression. The key point is, rather, to carry out
a more systematic delinking which also covers the field of state power
(replacing concentrated power with diffuse power), alienation (replacing
repressed life with intensity), and epistemology (replacing arborescent thought
with nomad thought).
The
problem is that Amin has not delinked enough: he remains linked to key aspects
of the modernist project, such as universalism, national integration and
economic growth. A delinking which breaks with capitalist logic might also
require decomposing the localised loci of hierarchical power. Local autonomy
ultimately leads to the prioritisation of subsistence over commodity
production, and hence of situated local belongings over states and nations. It
would require forms of diffuse power which override the centralised power of
the state and world-system, allowing local scales to predominate over the
global scale.
This
said, Amin’s work has been a huge inspiration to theorists seeking to move
beyond modernist conceptions, particularly in the subsistence perspective. It
is a necessary counterbalance to the emphasis on orthodox Marxism on the core
countries. It provides a clear sense of how global inequalities emerge and are
maintained.
Another
qualification should be added. Today’s world is not only characterised by
exploitation of peripheries, but increasingly, by phenomena of ‘forcible
delinking’. Certain poor countries, especially in Africa, are excluded from the
formal world economy almost entirely. So are many of the urban and rural poor.
Usually, forcible delinking correlates with widespread impoverishment, as
global connections are cut off with nothing to take their place (Though not
always. The fact that Somaliaperformed
better on most human
development criteria after the collapse of the state – and corresponding
disappearance of externally-focused economics, structural adjustment, and debt
repayments – is highly indicative for dependency theory).
Forcible
delinking is admittedly very different from what Amin has in mind. Yet it is a
sign of how capitalism tends to give its opponents what they want, but in distorted
form. Forcible delinking tends to produce a scramble for systemic inclusion and
a fear of delinking which acts to reinforce the denkverbot against questioning
global capitalism and international competitiveness.
This
is a predictable effect, echoing Frank’s discussions of Guatemala fifty years
ago. When an economy is organised towards external extraction, the sudden
withdrawal of such extraction leaves the economy ill-suited for anything else.
Exploitation comes to seem better than exclusion, but only because of the
‘distortions’ introduced by exploitation, and the lack of an alternative
vision.
Forcible
delinking also provides zones of marginality in which capitalist power is weak,
which can become sites of resistance and of alternative formations. This is
clear for instance in the case of Chiapas, in movements in the Andes, Manipur
and West Papua, and in a more ambiguous way in Somalia, Afghanistan and
Pakhtunkhwa.
Mainstream
security theory is awash with fears that the ‘black holes’ created by forcible
delinking will become sites of anti-systemic resistance. These fears are
exacerbated by the fact that these sites are connected into the world by new
communications technologies. While it has most often been used by reactive
movements, the potential of ‘black holes’ is also a potential site for a
politics of delinking.
I
would suggest that forcible delinking alters the series of steps through which
anti-systemic delinking can occur. Whereas Amin expects a popular movement to
form around a counter-project, take power, then institute delinking, today we
are faced with a situation of building popular movements in areas which have
already been delinked. We need, so to speak, to make a virtue out of the
necessity of forced delinking by turning it into a basis for constructing
autonomous zones.
Andrew
Robinson is a political theorist and activist
based in the UK. His book Power,
Resistance and Conflict in the Contemporary World: Social Movements, Networks
and Hierarchies (co-authored
with Athina Karatzogianni) was published in Sep 2009 by Routledge. His ‘In
Theory’ column appears every other Friday.
No comments:
Post a Comment